Show simple item record

Flows of capital and forms of industry in Europe, 1500–1900

dc.contributor.authorTilly, Charlesen_US
dc.date.accessioned2006-09-08T21:39:23Z
dc.date.available2006-09-08T21:39:23Z
dc.date.issued1983-03en_US
dc.identifier.citationTilly, Charles; (1983). "Flows of capital and forms of industry in Europe, 1500–1900." Theory and Society 12(2): 123-142. <http://hdl.handle.net/2027.42/43639>en_US
dc.identifier.issn0304-2421en_US
dc.identifier.issn1573-7853en_US
dc.identifier.urihttps://hdl.handle.net/2027.42/43639
dc.description.abstractAn unwary traveler in Paris or London often straightens out the river in his imagination, and then makes terrible deductions about the shortest path from one place to another within the city. If he follows up those deductions without consulting a well-drawn map, he finds himself wandering, worn, and confused. Neither the Seine nor the Thames comes close to describing a straight line. Similarly, a straight-line model of industrialization is not merely inaccurate in itself; it leads to faulty, costly deductions about the likely consequences and correlates of the whole process. The Industrial Revolution model of industrialization follows a straight line from agriculture to handicraft to full-scale industry, with handicraft a weak anticipation of full-scale industry. That model not only exaggerates the role of technology and foreshortens the history of industrial production, but also - at least for the European experience - misstates the relationships between urban and rural capital and labor. The classic Marxist model, with its intermediate stage of Manufacture drawing heavily on rural labor, improves our understanding of the historical terrain by putting an appropriate bend in the river of industrialization. It also improves on the Industrial Revolution model by drawing attention to the accumulation and redeployment of capital. Yet the classic Marxist model, too, exaggerates the importance of technological change, and underestimates the interdependence of changes in city and country, of alterations in the organization of industry and agriculture.en_US
dc.format.extent892203 bytes
dc.format.extent3115 bytes
dc.format.mimetypeapplication/pdf
dc.format.mimetypetext/plain
dc.language.isoen_US
dc.publisherKluwer Academic Publishers; Elsevier Science Publishers ; Springer Science+Business Mediaen_US
dc.subject.otherSocial Sciences, Generalen_US
dc.subject.otherSociologyen_US
dc.subject.otherPhilosophy of the Social Sciencesen_US
dc.titleFlows of capital and forms of industry in Europe, 1500–1900en_US
dc.typeArticleen_US
dc.subject.hlbsecondlevelSociologyen_US
dc.subject.hlbtoplevelSocial Sciencesen_US
dc.description.peerreviewedPeer Revieweden_US
dc.contributor.affiliationumCenter for Research on Social Organization, University of Michigan, USAen_US
dc.contributor.affiliationumcampusAnn Arboren_US
dc.description.bitstreamurlhttp://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/2027.42/43639/1/11186_2004_Article_BF00157009.pdfen_US
dc.identifier.doihttp://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF00157009en_US
dc.identifier.sourceTheory and Societyen_US
dc.owningcollnameInterdisciplinary and Peer-Reviewed


Files in this item

Show simple item record

Remediation of Harmful Language

The University of Michigan Library aims to describe library materials in a way that respects the people and communities who create, use, and are represented in our collections. Report harmful or offensive language in catalog records, finding aids, or elsewhere in our collections anonymously through our metadata feedback form. More information at Remediation of Harmful Language.

Accessibility

If you are unable to use this file in its current format, please select the Contact Us link and we can modify it to make it more accessible to you.