Selection institutions and war aims
dc.contributor.author | Smith, Alastair | en_US |
dc.contributor.author | Siverson, Randolph M. | en_US |
dc.contributor.author | Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce | en_US |
dc.contributor.author | Morrow, James D. | en_US |
dc.date.accessioned | 2006-09-11T19:31:53Z | |
dc.date.available | 2006-09-11T19:31:53Z | |
dc.date.issued | 2006-01 | en_US |
dc.identifier.citation | Morrow, James D.; Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce; Siverson, Randolph M.; Smith, Alastair; (2006). "Selection institutions and war aims." Economics of Governance 7(1): 31-52. <http://hdl.handle.net/2027.42/47901> | en_US |
dc.identifier.issn | 1435-6104 | en_US |
dc.identifier.issn | 1435-8131 | en_US |
dc.identifier.uri | https://hdl.handle.net/2027.42/47901 | |
dc.description.abstract | We explore how the sizes of the winning coalition and selectorate influence the war aims of states. Leaders who answer to a small winning coalition are more likely to seek territorial gain as a way to increase state resources. Nonterritorial war aims produce a commitment problem in that after the war the defeated state may not comply with the victor's demands. States with large winning coalitions are more willing to continue the war to remove the enemy leader as a solution to this commitment problem. We test our hypotheses against the Militarized Interstate Dispute data set, and we find some support for our argument. | en_US |
dc.format.extent | 128231 bytes | |
dc.format.extent | 3115 bytes | |
dc.format.mimetype | application/pdf | |
dc.format.mimetype | text/plain | |
dc.language.iso | en_US | |
dc.publisher | Springer-Verlag | en_US |
dc.subject.other | War Aims | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Political Science | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Public Finance & Economics | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Economics / Management Science | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Winning Coalition | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Economics General | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Interstate Conflict | en_US |
dc.subject.other | Postwar Commitment Problem | en_US |
dc.title | Selection institutions and war aims | en_US |
dc.type | Article | en_US |
dc.subject.hlbsecondlevel | Economics | en_US |
dc.subject.hlbtoplevel | Business | en_US |
dc.description.peerreviewed | Peer Reviewed | en_US |
dc.contributor.affiliationum | University of Michigan, 426 Thompson St, 4203 ISR, MI 48106-1248, Ann Arbor, USA | en_US |
dc.contributor.affiliationother | Department of Political Science, University of California, Davis, One Shields Ave, CA 95616, Davis, USA | en_US |
dc.contributor.affiliationother | Hoover Institution, CA 94305-6010, Stanford, USA | en_US |
dc.contributor.affiliationother | Department of Politics, New York University, 715 Broadway, 4th floor, NY 10003, USA | en_US |
dc.contributor.affiliationumcampus | Ann Arbor | en_US |
dc.description.bitstreamurl | http://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/2027.42/47901/1/10101_2005_Article_108.pdf | en_US |
dc.identifier.doi | http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10101-005-0108-z | en_US |
dc.identifier.source | Economics of Governance | en_US |
dc.owningcollname | Interdisciplinary and Peer-Reviewed |
Files in this item
Accessibility: If you are unable to use this file in its current format, please select the Contact Us link and we can modify it to make it more accessible to you.